How China’s Socialism Outperforms Capitalist Development Strategies

来源 :CHINA TODAY | 被引量 : 0次 | 上传用户:anabaow1a1
下载到本地 , 更方便阅读
声明 : 本文档内容版权归属内容提供方 , 如果您对本文有版权争议 , 可与客服联系进行内容授权或下架
论文部分内容阅读
  CHINA has followed an economic development strategy, as analyzed below, that is radically different from the neo-liberal “Washington Consensus” advocated by the IMF. The latter is the dominant development strategy advocated by capitalist countries. This article therefore factually compares the results of what will be termed China’s“socialist development strategy” versus the Washington Consensus.
  The reasons for making such a factual comparison are clear. The basis of any serious or scientifi c analysis is that if facts and theory do not coincide it is the theory that has to be abandoned, not the facts suppressed. This is equally expressed in the Chinese dictum “seek truth from facts.” Anti-scientific “dogmatism” consists of clinging to a theory even when the facts contradict it.
  Despite this requirement for factual study, supporters of the Washington Consensus appear to dislike making systematic factual comparisons of the two development approaches. The reasons for this will become evident from the data below. This shows that China’s“socialist development strategy” far outperforms the Washington Consensus. The emphasis placed by China on development strategy and its socialist orientation has obvious implications for other countries.
  The term “Washington Consensus” was fi rst coined in 1989 by U.S.-based economist John Williamson –although the actual practical policies were commenced in the late 1970s/early 1980s. The Washington Consensus is a classic form of neo-liberalism. It advocates in terms of economic policy privatization and minimization of the state’s economic role. Its social policy may be described as “trickle down” – a belief that if there is economic growth all layers of society will automatically benefi t as the benefi ts “trickle down” from the richest to poorest. Legally the Washington Consensus states that the overriding goal is the strongest guarantee of private property. Politically, although claiming to be neutral, this combination of policies evidently favours capitalist and conservative political parties.
  China’s “socialist development strategy,” which commenced with its 1978 economic reforms, is radically different in its entire framework, and directly counterposed on key policy issues. China used, in Xi Jinping’s phraseology on economic policy, both the “visible” and the “invisible hand” – not simply the private sector but also the state. Indeed, in China itself, as the Communiqué of the Third Plenary Session of the 18th Central Committee of the CPC stated: “We must unswervingly consolidate and develop the public economy, persist in the dominant position of public ownership, give full play to the leading role of the state-owned sector.”   In social policy China, in line with its socialist approach:
  undertakes conscious programs deliberately aimed at eradicating poverty – these are to be completed in the 13th Five-Year Plan by 2020 by lifting the remaining 70 million people out of poverty;
  deliberately promotes development through urbanization as a way of moving the population into higher productivity economic sectors;
  deliberately seeks to narrow the income gap between rural and urban areas;
  does not rely exclusively on “the market” but deliberately uses state infrastructure spending to raise the economic level of its less developed inland provinces;
  legally guarantees private property but a key economic role is assigned to the state sector;
  is politically socialist;
  What, therefore, were the factual outcomes of these two radically different approaches to economic development? To assess this, for reasons which will become evident from the statistics, not only will China itself be analyzed but three other countries also considered. These are Vietnam, which defines itself as socialist and which in reality drew heavily from China’s “socialist market economy” approach, Cambodia, and the Lao People’s Democratic Republic – the latter two also highly influenced by China’s development model.
  The facts are summarized in Table 1 which shows the annual average rate of per capita GDP growth to 2015 from 1978, when China began its economic reforms, from 1989, when the Washington Consensus was put forward, and from 1993, when data for Cambodia becomes available.
  The data is of course extremely striking – indeed conclusive. From 1993 to 2015, when availability of data allows all four countries to be analyzed, China, Cambodia, Vietnam, and Laos ranked respectively first, second, and third, and fourth in world per capita GDP growth. Peripheral cases of countries with populations of less than five million or dominated by oil production are not included. From 1989, the year of the putting forward of the Washington Consensus, to 2015, China, Vietnam and Laos ranked respectively first, second, and third in the world as regards per capita GDP growth. From 1978 onwards China ranked first among all economies in terms of economic growth.
  The degree to which economies influenced by the China development model outgrew the world average was huge. From 1978 onwards China’s rate of growth was almost six times the world average. Since 1989 China again grew almost six times as fast as the world average while Vietnam and Laos grew over three times as fast.   The contrasts not only of average per capita GDP growth but of eradication of poverty were overwhelming. From 1981 China lifted 728 million people out of World Bank-defined poverty. Another socialist country, Vietnam, lifted over 30 million from poverty by the same criteria. The whole of the rest of the world, in which the dominant model advocated by the IMF was the Washington Consensus, lifted only 120 million people out of poverty. In summary, 83 percent of the reduction of the number of those living in poverty occurred in China, and 85 percent in socialist countries. Only 15 percent of the reduction in number of those living in poverty occurred in capitalist countries.
  This data, of course, also refutes the claim that capitalism and free market policies produced rapid economic growth and poverty reduction. If capitalism were the motor of rapid economic growth and poverty reduction, then this growth should be fastest and poverty reduction greatest in capitalist countries. Instead it is in socialist China and socialist Vietnam that the greatest poverty reduction has taken place. Socialist China and socialist Vietnam, together with the countries they influence, Cambodia and Laos, also saw the fastest economic growth.
  The success of China’s conscious development policies is crucial to world economic growth. This is particularly true in the difficult slow-growth global economic conditions following the international financial crisis –accurately described as the “new mediocre.” Economic development remains the most fundamental issue for the overwhelming majority of the world’s population. According to the latest World Bank data, 84 percent of the world’s population lives in developing countries.
  The facts of world economic development show that China’s development policies that include a key role for the state sector, clear urbanization policies, large-scale conscious policies to eradicate poverty, and a socialist political orientation were most successful in producing both economic growth and poverty reduction. This has clear implications for the world economy.
  The simple but decisive fact that the world’s first, second, third, and fourth most rapidly growing economies all use the “China socialist development model” is a factual demonstration of its superiority to any alternative approach – and in particular to the Washington Consensus.
其他文献
CHINA has experienced huge changes since the launch of the reform and opening-up policy in 1978. But it wasn’t just economic influence that spilled in from abroad; the door also opened wide in a cultu
期刊
INNOVATION is rightly seen as key to China’s economic future. But because it is so crucial it is vital to study the real facts regarding the forces determining innovation – rather than myths. These wi
期刊
THe earliest Chinese paintings appeared about 4,700 years ago. The patterns and designs on clothes and utensils, including pottery, during the Shang and Zhou dynasties (c. 1600-256 BC), are testament
期刊
I’VE had few experiences as bu- colic as gliding downriver past weeping willows and under the 36 arched bridges of 1700-yearold Zhujiajiao Water Town – “Shanghai’s Venice of China.” Zhujiajiao is a Ch
期刊
THe Sino-U.S. relationship is one of the most significant bilateral ties in the world. The ballast in this relationship –economic and trade cooperation – is at the same time a key engine driving globa
期刊
NEW Zealand Prime Minister John Key paid an official visit to China in April 2016, accompanied by a high-level delegation composed of ministers, parliamentarians and some 40 entrepreneurs. Key and his
期刊
TONG Ren Tang, leading producer of traditional Chinese medicines (TCM), has for years promoted its products through a global strategy that has made it a popular brand in such diverse cities as Sydney,
期刊
THE mellow bel canto singing, in clearly articulated Mandarin, of an American soprano in the role of Jin Zi, heroine of the opera The Savage Land staged at the China Conservatory of Music concert hall
期刊
THREE years later, the dramatic arbitration on the South China Sea issue choreographed by the Philippines approaches its end. Since the U.S. inflated the South China Sea issue at the 2010 meeting of f
期刊
ECHOING the G20 Hangzhou Summit, the Civil Society 20(C20), one of the five G20 outreach groups, opened on July 5, 2016 in Qingdao, Shandong Province. Focusing on “poverty eradication, green developme
期刊