Reforming China’s SOEs

来源 :CHINA TODAY | 被引量 : 0次 | 上传用户:liongliong463
下载到本地 , 更方便阅读
声明 : 本文档内容版权归属内容提供方 , 如果您对本文有版权争议 , 可与客服联系进行内容授权或下架
论文部分内容阅读
  CHINA is currently carrying out major changes in its State-owned Enterprises (SOEs) in a framework set by the third plenum of the Chinese Communist Party’s current Central Committee. This resolved: “We must unswervingly consolidate and develop the public economy, persist in the dominant position of public ownership, and give full play to the leading role of the state-owned sector.”
  That China sees SOEs as the core of its economy is the key structural feature distinguishing China’s “socialist market economy” from the West’s “private market economy.”
  Given that China’s economic system has outstripped capitalist market economies for over 30 years, what is the connection between China’s SOEs and its superior rate of economic development? Why has a “dominant position of public ownership” produced higher economic performance, and what are the specific problems leading to SOE reform? The answer to these questions indicates what the changes should be.
  SOEs give China clear micro- and macro-economic advantages. The first micro-economic one is that as SOEs do not have private owners they do not pay dividends to private shareholders. Dividends are a significant proportion of Western economies – around five percent of U.S. GDP. In China profits which in the West would be dividend payments to private shareholders can instead be invested by SOEs. As Western private shareholders use part of their dividends for their consumption needs, therefore, SOEs raise the Chinese economy’s overall investment level. As investment is a chief driver of economic growth this enhances China’s economic performance.
  SOEs second micro-economic advantage is that the state, and therefore state-backed companies, pay lower interest rates for borrowing than private companies –due to lower risk.
  SOEs’ macro-economic advantages are even greater than the micro-economic ones. In a private economy no automatic mechanism ensures that company profits, which technically are a form of saving, are transformed into productive investment. Keynes put this in a famous comparison: “Saving means – so to speak – a decision not to have dinner today. But it does not necessitate a decision to have dinner… a week hence.”
  The theoretical possibility that private company savings will not be invested operates practically. A key mechanism leading to the 2008 international financial crisis was that U.S. companies did not invest all their profits. U.S. company operating surpluses rose substantially, from 20 percent of Gross Domestic Income (GDI) in 1980 to 26 percent in 2013, while simultaneously U.S. private fixed investment fell from 19 percent of GDI in 1979 to 15 percent in 2013. Falling investment, despite rising profits, led to economic slowdown and eventually financial crisis.   This situation has continued with the accumulation of U.S. companies’ “cash mountains.” By mid-2013 U.S. non-financial companies’ cash holdings reached US $1.5 trillion.
  U.S. companies, instead of investing, transferred money to shareholders not only in dividends but via share buy-backs. In 2014 U.S. S&P 500 companies spent 95 percent of their operating margins on buying their own shares or on dividends. Failure to invest meant that by 2013 the average age of U.S. fixed assets reached 22 years, the oldest since 1956.
  As Larry Fink, head of BlackRock, the world’s largest asset manager, noted: “More and more corporate leaders have responded with actions that can deliver immediate returns to shareholders…while underinvesting in innovation, skilled workforces or essential capital expenditures necessary to sustain long-term growth.” The U.S. government can appeal for greater investment, but no mechanism exists to enforce this on private companies.
  In contrast, in China state ownership of SOEs means they can, if necessary, be instructed to invest. This is a key reason why China’s investment level is far higher than the U.S.’s – in 2013, the latest internationally comparable figures, China devoted 45.9 percent of GDP to fixed investment compared to the U.S.’s 18.9 percent.
  China’s ability to directly control investment through the state sector also creates stronger tools of macroeconomic anti-crisis management than in Western economies. As the Wall Street Journal noted: “Most economies can pull two levers to bolster growth: fiscal and monetary. China has a third option. The National Development and Reform Commission can accelerate the flow of investment projects.”
  This ability to set investment levels via its state sector is a key reason why China has strongly outperformed the U.S. since the beginning of the international financial crisis. From 2007 to 2014 China’s GDP grew by 79.9 percent versus 8.2 percent in the U.S. – China’s economy grew almost 10 times as fast as the U.S.’s.
  But if SOEs overall give China huge advantages, what problems are the new changes designed to tackle? There are many individual issues but these are best understood in fundamental economic terms.
  In China an error was made in the past of seeing SOEs as not just bringing economic benefits but performing a social function. SOEs not only provided employment but social security such as housing, health care, etc. This was an error for two reasons. First, providing such services increases SOEs costs – eroding or eliminating their advantage in terms of lower borrowing costs and not having to pay dividends to private shareholders.   Second, effective management requires specialization and focus. Company managers need to concentrate on their firms’ efficient functioning, while those delivering social protection need to concentrate on that. Trying to do both simultaneously inevitably leads to neither being done with utmost efficiency. SOEs should contribute to social protection by tax payments, not social security management. Remnants of this old system need to be eliminated.
  Clearly demarcating SOEs purely economic functioning and enforcing financial discipline is aided by ensuring larger parts of their assets are in companies listed on share markets. This principle was followed in the recent reorganization of a major SOE, Shanghai Electric Group, which transferred assets from its unlisted parent company to a listed subsidiary.
  Second, competition powerfully stimulates economic efficiency. But it must be understood within a globalized economy, not purely domestically. This is another feature of current SOE reform. To take a leading example, China previously had two state-owned railway construction companies – CNR and CSR. The theory was that their competition would stimulate efficiency.
  But in reality, particularly in global competition in high speed trains, Chinese firms’ key rivals are international ones. Even the US $32.3 billion combined turnover of the two Chinese companies is far behind world leader Siemens’ US $96.5 billion – and China’s manufacturers also face competition from Japan’s bullet trains and Canada’s Bombardier. China’s merging of its two companies correctly flows from understanding competition in global, not domestic, terms.
  This further relates to a more general question. Global data clearly show large companies have higher productivity than small ones. The greater role played by large companies in the U.S. is a key reason for its superior productivity compared to competitors – 45 percent of U.S. employment is in companies with more than 250 employees, compared to only 33 percent in the EU.
  But China has over 100,000 SOEs – requiring consolidation. Taking the largest currently discussed proposals that the 112 centrally owned SOEs be merged into 30-50 goes in the right direction. This should be part of China’s general company consolidation – it is uncompetitive, for example, for China to have over 10 major automobile manufacturers compared to three in the U.S.
  Finally, a key question is monopoly. Competition spurs efficiency but in some sectors it cannot operate normally because investment costs are too high to accommodate competing systems. No country has competing electricity grids or metro systems.   Faced with inherent monopolies, a “market solution”is the last thing required. The market operations of monopolies are well understood – they feature excessive prices and inferior quality. Inherent monopolies require an “anti-market solution” – keeping them in state ownership and imposing tough management to overcome their market tendencies. This is a key reason for the necessity to create a cadre of highly trained and tough state enterprise managers.
  The fight against corruption is one aspect of that. In 2014, 70 SOE executives were placed under investigations for corruption which continued through to 2015. But an overall system of highly efficient state managers must be created.
  In this regard, while the author is in general a strong supporter of China’s economic policy, he disagrees with one of China’s policies. Deng Xiaoping, famously noted that in China’s current “primary stage of socialism” payment must be “according to work.” He restated Marx. In strict social terms a manager is a very skilled worker. In every country, including the U.S., despite media myths, the overwhelming majority of large companies are run by managers not by “entrepreneurs” – the owners of the companies. The reason these managers are so highly paid is that the work they do is ultra-skilled – decisions which can involve billions of dollars.
  Singapore has the system most in accord with “payment according to work.” Managers are highly paid but subject to transparency and treated as workers – they can be easily sacked. It is because this is in accord with economic principles that Singapore has one of the most skilled, and non-corrupt, management systems in the world.
  This approach of high SOE manager payment, however, is not China’s current system and would be extremely unpopular there.
其他文献
JUST 10 km as the crow flies from Tian’anmen Square on Beijing’s west fourth ring road is Meinuo Garden, Xue Lu and her husband Li He’s succulent plant greenhouse. Compared to other horticultural cent
期刊
TO commemorate the cente- nary of Israel Epstein’s birth, in 2014 the Shanghai-based Oriental Publishing Center published Epstein and Soong Ching Ling’s Biography, a Chinese-language account of the pr
期刊
AN 8.1-magnitude earthquake struck Nepal at 11:56 am on April 25 local time. The quake was so huge it affected neighboring China’s Tibet Autonomous Region. By 00:00 am the next day, Xigaze in the sout
期刊
WHEN the Ebola pandemic took hold in West Africa last February, China’s government took immediate action. It sent around 10 teams of experts and medics to the affected countries, amounting to 1,000 pe
期刊
IN 2015, as China’s state-owned enterprises (SOE) cautiously propel reforms, they find themselves in a new predicament – that of a decline in business performance while under the government anticorrup
期刊
INTERNATIONAL relations often mimic interper- sonal relationships, insofar as should one party want to break away from past habits or conventions, he or she is likely to meet arguments and obstruction
期刊
Everyone knows that China is the world’s factory. But only after reading this book do I feel that I know what Chinese workers are like on a personal level. They are strong and vital, and not at all th
期刊
AT the end of May the second phase of Niu Jian’s sustainable living lab project was completed at Beijing’s International Camping Park. It is designed as a training camp that helps citizens make the tr
期刊
A major step towards reform of China’s prop- erty management took place on March 1, 2015, with the State Council’s issuance of the provisional regulations on real estate registration.  China’s modern
期刊
COULD Motorola reclaim its glory days? Many consumers pondered this question when Lenovo bought Motorola Mobility for US $2.91 billion in 2014. The acquisition brought the former internationally famou
期刊